How might the next big market crash unfold?

In the second part of their discussion Tim Price, Dan Denning and Nick O’Connor talk about what the government and central banks could have done differently in 2008, and how the next collapse might unfold.

You can read the first part of the conversation here.

Dan Denning: Two people were the ‘buyers of last resort’ during the financial crisis of 2008. First, it was the mugs who didn’t know what was going on, and then it was the Fed who did know what was going on, but stepped in with all of these other asset purchase programmes to provide liquidity in markets where it had disappeared.

My question is: if we get something like that again – whether it’s in corporate junk, high yield or even in sovereign bonds, which I think is possible – will we see the same response from central banks, and can you hypothesise about what the effect would be on interest rates and/or currencies?

Tim Price: It’s an excellent question, but I’m not sure that history can necessarily repeat. So in 2007/08, the corporate sector – specifically the banks – were bailed out and the bank debt problems effectively shunted onto the sovereign balance sheet. Now the problem is much more severe. This isn’t just a suggestion, it’s fact. The McKinsey study earlier this year pointed out that global debt has actually risen since Lehman’s failed. So the idea that mysteriously the world has de-levered is just a complete nonsense. It’s a false narrative.

The world is more heavily indebted now than it was before, but the difference is governments are no longer in a position to sustain being buyers of last resort. Governments and central banks can’t do it – even the Fed can’t do it, because the Fed’s already teetering on the brink of insolvency by any banking standards. So the only answer would be that we find a planet in a solar system that’s got inhabitants that are willing to take on this crap.

Dan: Why couldn’t they do it, though? The Fed expanded its balance sheet to something over $4trn. The ECB (European Central Bank), the BOJ (Bank of Japan) and even maybe the Bank of International Settlements, and the IMF (International Monetary Fund) – isn’t there some balance sheet flexibility left, not with sovereign governments anymore, but with central banks? It’s not real money for them…

Tim: This is true, so they can expand the balance sheets further and buy equities even (which is already happening in Japan). That’s a fabulous game if you can do that. If you happen to be a central bank, you’re creating money out of nothing and then buying assets of real value – profitable, commercial enterprises’ equity – with those assets. But at some point to me at least, the marginal investor is going to be watching this fun and games and thinking: “They’re creating money out of nowhere and then they’ve bought real assets with it. This is magic – but this is magic, this is not reality.”

Dan: Well, I think that’s an important point, because it shows that that’s what’s different about now from 2008/09 – the credibility of central banks is what’s on the line. Last time it was the private sector, and everybody had fun or relished the idea that it was the evil investment banks, and some of them got what was coming and some of them probably shouldn’t have been bailed out. But the system itself wasn’t jeopardised because central banks stepped in to provide liquidity.

But what’s at stake now is that as people look at that, they start asking these questions, well, how does that work? How is it that the Fed can, expand its balance sheet to create $4trn where none existed before? How does that solve a debt problem? And I think the more people think about that, the more they say, well, that system doesn’t work. That doesn’t make sense to a lot of people.

Tim: James Grant of Grant’s Interest Rate Observer has described this very well. In his eyes we are seeing the failure of what he calls “the PhD standard”. So we previously had the gold standard – Bretton Woods ended in 1971 when Nixon tool the dollar off gold, and severed the last vestiges of backing for a paper currency. So since then, for the last 40-odd years, we’ve had a pure experiment in paper money. That has never ever worked – in the fullness of time, these things have always failed. But nevertheless, the experiment goes on. And now, instead of having a gold standard, we have a PhD standard, whereby economists of a certain persuasion are calling all the shots.

And I think you’ve hit the nail on the head – the key word here is confidence. For as long as people have confidence in the system, then the system lasts. But whether it’s confidence in the system, a central banking philosophy, or a currency, these things do not operate in a linear fashion. The confidence lasts until it breaks, but it doesn’t break piece by piece. Suddenly the branch just snaps from the tree. So as and when this does become a bigger problem, it will happen very quickly.

Dan: Which is related to our whole focus in the last three months on cash – because that is an expression of people’s confidence either that things are going to be fine and you can go to the bank and get your money, or that things are not fine, and I want my money in my hand. That I think is why we’ve seen – quite deliberately from official and unofficial idea leaders of the mainstream – an attack on the idea of cash, because cash is how you vote in the financial system. A vote of no confidence is to take your money out of the bank. If you can’t take your money out of the bank because there’s no cash, then you can’t withdraw your confidence from the financial system – you’re locked into it.

Tim: I think there’s a quote we used in the book, The War on Cash, the Hemingway quote, where someone says: “How did you go bankrupt?” And he said: “two ways – slowly and then all at once”.

Nick O’Connor: When gold was roaring up to $1,900 an ounce, that was what people said – that it was a vote of no confidence. A vote of no confidence in the system was to buy gold. It was maybe not necessarily how people thought about it when they were investing in gold, but en masse that’s what it was. It’s kind of the same thing.

Tim: But we’re seeing that in reverse now because gold’s trading at around $1,000 an ounce which effectively implies there is more or less total confidence in the central bank PhD standard.

Nick: Or you could argue that gold being high was a signal of no confidence, and then it was people buying bitcoin, and now it’s cash. You could argue that the way that people show their dissatisfaction and lack of confidence in the system isn’t always manifested in the price of one asset.

Dan: I think that’s also a major difference between now and the last financial crisis. The move in gold had some retail element to it – people who had never bought gold before, and had never really thought about the value of money. For the first time they thought: “Well, maybe I should do this. It might be a reasonable position to hedge against the possibility that there’s something seriously wrong”. But I would say that most of the move came from people who were already in the investment markets. A lot of the liquidity came from exchange traded funds. So there was a lot of investment demand as part of the gold price. The difference now I think, and this is why cash is more interesting than gold as a reflection of what people are actually thinking is, everybody uses cash.

Tim: Yes, gold is a luxury and cash is a staple.

Dan: Right, to me it just shows that the stakes have been raised. In 2008, it was the viability of the financial sector and the credit that consumers and businesses could get. It’s just ratcheted up to another level, and as you said, Tim, moved onto the sovereign balance sheet. And when it’s on the sovereign balance sheet and central banks have to step in and finance things, then a lot more is at stake. I think people sense that right now, but not as many people understand what that means, which is kind of why you wrote the book, The War on Cash, to show what’s at stake in this conversation.

Nick: There are two key phrases that I’ve picked up from this discussion so far. You talked about it being ‘like magic’. You can “create money from nowhere and buy something real” – that is like magic. And it’s the same with confidence, right. It’s like a confidence trick. You have to keep people believing that it’s magic.

Tim: It’s a faith-based system. I mean you could argue that any asset ultimately derives its value from faith in it – whether that’s gold, the stockmarket, bonds and currencies, whatever.

Nick: But the thing that I think is interesting is – there’s no such thing as magic, so really it’s an illusion that they can do this without consequences. That’s the trick. So they’re really trying to pull the wool over our eyes. You can create lots of money from nowhere, buy stuff and there are no adverse consequences on the other side. It’s the illusion that we live in a world without consequences now, and really the work that we do tends to try to unravel that myth and show that there are consequences for all of these actions. They’re just perhaps not the ones that you would expect.

Tim: The metaphor of the broken windows fallacy is possibly one of the best-known ideas in classical economics. The French economist Frederic Bastiat uses the example of a shopkeeper. A little boy throws a brick through the shopkeeper’s window – I think it’s a baker in the original French. So the shopkeeper now has to buy a new window and a crowd gathers and there’s a bit of a commotion. The people in the crowd say, well, it’s a bit of a shame for the shopkeeper but look it on the other hand, the glazier is going to get some money now and the glazier can do stuff that he previously couldn’t do. So maybe actually we should go and smash all the windows – I think that’s an argument that’s been taken ad absurdum by the likes of Paul Krugman.

The problem with that analysis is there’s that which is seen – which is the broken window and the money that the glazier gets – and that which is unseen – the money that the shopkeeper had and that he can no longer spend, because he’s had to give it to glazier. That’s unforeseen consequences. That’s what would happen to all of the purchasing power that central banks are destroying by printing money, and giving it to the banking sector or whoever. Wherever it’s ending up, it’s not ending up with the man in the street, it’s ending up in a very privileged part of the financial elite and I would suggest that the greatest trick central banks ever pulled off was making people believe that central banks exist to serve the interests of the people. They exist to serve the interests of the banking sector.

Dan: I think that’s an important point. I’ve had this argument with people who are economists and they say: “well, it doesn’t really matter whether the window is broken or not, because the important thing is to create more money”. That once the money is created and someone spends it, it then has that multiplier effect throughout the economy. So what if the baker doesn’t get to spend his $50 on a new window? The glazier has it and he’s going to spend it on something – and that money didn’t exist before.

What they miss with that, and what is unseen, is not the choice that the baker no longer makes because he has to replace the window, it’s the fact that he loses his choice. His freedom, his financial freedom is what he loses, because he is no longer free to choose what to do with his money. That choice has been made for him by someone’s act of destruction. And it is really absurd when you take Krugman’s point to its logical limit – and actually he did this himself – kind of bemusedly saying that the best thing for a global recovery would be if aliens attacked the planet.

Tim: Or that we had another world war.

Dan: Yes, that’s the logical conclusion, and no right-thinking, freedom-loving, liberal-order-appreciating person would say that the best way to promote prosperity is total war. That’s the absurdity at the kernel of their argument.

 

• If you want to listen to the whole podcast, it is available here.

Category: Market updates

From time to time we may tell you about regulated products issued by Southbank Investment Research Limited. With these products your capital is at risk. You can lose some or all of your investment, so never risk more than you can afford to lose. Seek independent advice if you are unsure of the suitability of any investment. Southbank Investment Research Limited is authorised and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority. FCA No 706697. https://register.fca.org.uk/.

Š 2021 Southbank Investment Research Ltd. Registered in England and Wales No 9539630. VAT No GB629 7287 94.
Registered Office: 2nd Floor, Crowne House, 56-58 Southwark Street, London, SE1 1UN.

Terms and conditions | Privacy Policy | Cookie Policy | FAQ | Contact Us | Top ↑